Pages

Thursday, March 5, 2015

Negative Interest Rates, the ZLB, and True Capitalists


After six years of low interest rates many yields are now crossing the zero percent boundary. Interest rates in Europe and Australia have turned negative on some government and corporate bonds. The decline of these interest rates into negative territory has caused much consternation among two groups of observers.

The first group astonished by this development are those who believed interest rates were pegged by the 'zero lower bound' (ZLB). Interest rates were not supposed to go below zero percent because one could always hold physical cash and earn zero percent rather than holding bank accounts that earned a negative interest rate. Consequently, a breaching of the ZLB has been mind-blowing for some folks. Here, for example, is Matt Yglesias:
Something really weird is happening in Europe. Interest rates on a range of debt... have gone negative.In my experience, ordinary people are not especially excited about this. But among finance and economic types, I promise you that it's a huge deal — the economics equivalent of stumbling into a huge scientific discovery entirely by accident.
Paul Krugman similarly observes that crossing the ZLB is something he never expected. While many are surprised, the key idea behind the ZLB still holds. At some point it will become worthwhile to hold cash rather than bank deposits earning a negative return. It is just not at zero percent because of storage costs as recently noted by Evan Soltas and David Keohane. So if interest rates continue to fall they will eventually hit the effective lower bound and currency demand will soar.  

It is worth pointing out that JP Koning has been making this point about storage costs and the ZLB for a long time. For example, he had a post back in 2014 discussing the implications of the ECB's large €500 note for ZLB:
The ECB has differentiated itself from almost all other developed country central banks by issuing a mega-large note denomination, the €500 note... The €500 note creates a uniquely European problem because its large real value reduces the cost of storing cash and therefore raises the eurozone's lower bound. Think about it this way. To get $1 million in cash you need ten thousand $100 bills. With the €500 note, you need only 1,545 banknotes, or about one-eighth the volume of dollar notes required to get to $1 million. This means that owners of euros require less vault space for the same real quantity of funds, allowing them to reduce storage costs as well as shipping & handling expenses. In other words, the €500 note is far more convenient than the $100 note, the €100, the £100, the ¥10,000, or any other note out there (we'll ignore the Swiss). Thus if Draghi were to reduce rates to -0.25%, or even -0.35%, the existence of the not-so-inconvenient €500 very quickly begins to provide a very worthy alternative to negative yielding ECB deposits. The lower bound isn't so low anymore.

All the more reason to remove the €500 note in order to provide the ECB with further downward flexibility in interest rates. If the existence of the €500 note means that Draghi can't push rates below, say, -0.35% without mass cash conversion occurring... but the removal of said note from circulation allows him to drop that rate to -0.65% before the cash tipping point, then he's bought himself an extra three rate reductions by removing the €500.
So in addition to its problematic monetary policy, the ECB also has a €500 note that makes it harder for interest rates to reach their market-clearing levels. (Yes, this is a currency union that seems designed for failure.) Institutional details matter and JP Konign is one of the best on this when it comes to monetary policy. 

So the ZLB is still binding in spirit if not exactly at zero percent. Fortunately, there are ways to get around it without eliminating currency.

The second group that finds the move into negative interest rates unsettling do so for a different reason. They see it as another step by central banks to artificially push down interest rates. This is problematic for some, like Bill Gross, because it means financial markets are being distorted. For others, like Robert Higgs, the low-interest rate policy is troubling because it is causing the immiseration of people living on interest income

In both cases the premise is that central banks are causing interest rates to remain low. But this premise assumes too much. It could be the case that central banks over the past six years were adjusting their interest rate targets to match where the market-clearing or 'natural' interest rate was going. That is, as the economy weakened interest rates naturally would have fallen and, given the severity of the crisis, may have gone well below zero. Central banks were simply attempting to follow the market-clearing interest rate down, but decided to stop at zero percent because they believed they could not go any further. Even though we now know monetary authorities had some wiggle room left beneath zero percent, they still would have been constrained by the effective lower bound had they kept pushing.

The irony of this is that the Bill Gross and Robert Higgs of the world, who usually are free-market advocates, should be in favor of allowing interest rates to fall when necessary. They believe in the power of prices to clear markets, so they should be open to the possibility that sometimes--in severe crises like the Great Depression or Great Recessions--interest rates may need to go negative in order to clear output markets. If so, it is incorrect for them to ascribe the low interest rates to Fed policy since it was simply chasing after a falling natural interest rate. 

This understanding also means that the effective lower bound on interest rates is a price floor that distorts markets. And any good capitalist worth his salt should be in favor of abolishing this price floor and allowing prices to work. On this point, Paul Krugman is a better capitalist than Bill Gross or Robert Higgs since Krugman believes interest rates are low because of the economy, not the Fed.

That the market-clearing interest rate turned negative over the past six has been borne out in multiple studies. One prominent study that shows this is a 2012 Peter Ireland paper in the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. Another example comes from Michael Darda of MKM Partners. He estimates the market clearing interest rate by looking at the historical relationship between the federal funds rate and slack in the prime-age working force plus a risk premium. His estimated market clearing interest rate--the estimated Wicksellian equilibrium nominal short rate--also shows a negative value over this period.


So be careful when thinking about interest rates. They may be negative for good reasons.

P.S. Ramesh Ponnuru and I make the same point about negative market-clearing rates on the pages of the National Review, though we suggest an alternative approach that would avoid hitting the ZLB in the first place. We are hoping to reach out to our fellow conservatives who fail to see this point. This understanding also has implications for the balance-sheet view of the recession.

11 comments:

  1. The estimate by Michael Darda uses slack in the prime-age work force. Does he adjust the potential of employment for after the crisis? Do we still have the same potential? Are we in an attempt to return to a potential that is effectively out of reach? As your post describes, there are "effective" limits. Even employment may have a different effective limit after the crisis for various reasons. If you adjust that effective limit on employing prime-age workers, the short-term nominal equilibrium rate may actually be positive. And by lowering nominal rates to reach that unreachable level, will the economy heal enough to revive its prior potential? Do we just hold out hope that the economy will revive to prior normal levels? If not, the Fed rate will be caught short when a lower effective limit is reached.
    The economy is definitely sub-optimal and ill. Having nominal rates either too high or too low for too long will weaken the economy. So when nominal rates stay too low for too long, the economy weakens on the inside making the case to have even lower rates. We then have a self-fulfilling prophecy to drive down nominal rates further.
    Where are we really?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Great questions Edward. My sense is that the US natural rate is near to or crossing the zero boundary. Hence, the Fed's calls to tighten later this year make sense to me. But as your questions point out, these are only estimations fraught with errors.

      In the case of the Eurozone, though, I feel more certain that the natural rate is still negative especially in the periphery.

      Delete
  2. David, thank you for the insightful post. It drives me nuts when the 2-and-20 crowd whines about the Fed "distorting the markets" with zero rates. Why do they think they are entitled to a high risk-free interest rate? In calling for higher rates during times of a low natural rate, they are demanding a big government subsidy for their unproductive enterprise. You have it exactly right, the ELB is an unfortunate price floor that distorts markets, while the Fed is purely trying to ensure that the rates it influences follow the natural rate as much as possible, helping maintain a stable price level as the markets seek equilibrium between aggregate supply and aggregate demand.

    -Ken

    Kenneth Duda
    Menlo Park, CA

    ReplyDelete
  3. The desperate lengths you guys go to defend these psychotic central banks is truly hilarious. To argue that the fed has been following, rather than leading interest rates down is plainly ridiculous. The natural rate of interest is a mythical unicorn that used to thrive when we didn't have money printers to fox all our problems. Can't wait for Krugman to call for even more negative rates as his magical elixir of prosperity.

    ReplyDelete
  4. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/500_euro_note

    The value of this note to organised crime is well known and touched on in the link above. Spain seems to have a high proportion of the notes in circulation. This is not surprising as it is the major hideout for many European criminals, including British and Irish. Many deals are made there and although the drugs may not pass through Spain itself the money does. But I don't suppose that is very relevant to the main point of the post.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. am, that is interesting and makes sense. Thanks for sharing.

      Delete
  5. "To argue that the fed has been following, rather than leading interest rates down is plainly ridiculous."

    Evidence?

    ReplyDelete
  6. Is a low-negative IR a prove of secular stagnation?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Not necessarily, it could simply be low and negative because of sharp recession. See my piece with Ramesh Ponnuru here: http://people.wku.edu/david.beckworth/secularstagnation.pdf

      Delete
  7. Tripe. CB/NB reconciliation 9/22/08 - 9/22/14.

    M2 (excluding MMMFs, which declined), exceeded POMOs by $184.2 billion. But then you must add $626 billion (2011 figure), from the expansion of bank capital accounts. Then you can subtract the expansion of CB credit (which includes the CUs, S&Ls, and MSBs which I estimated), of $1,804 trillion.

    Net, you get that POMOs were $994 billion short of matching IBDDs (excess reserves).

    Virtually no money growth from QE, i.e., a dramatic short-fall in AD. And AD suffered as savings were further impounded within the System due to the countercyclical increase in bank capital, and the FDIC's unlimited transaction deposit insurance (which together with remunerating excess reserve balances, radically decimated Vt). Indeed funds were siphoned out from all over the world, diluting m1, Vi, and giving economists false signposts. E.g., the FBOs were incentivized to buy sovereign debt.

    Negative rates (a lack of safe-assets), resulted from non-existent Treasury-Reserve bank collaboration. Whereas the CBs bought short-term debt between 1942 and 2008, it wasn't profitable after remunerating reserves. The purchase of zero risk weighted assets from the non-bank public was circumvented.

    Interest rates are the price of loan-funds, not the price of money; the price of money is represented by the various price (indices) level; and inflation is the most important factor determining interest rates, operating as it does through both the demand for and the supply of loan-funds. Ergo, the Fed failed again.

    ReplyDelete
  8. As Milton Friedman pointed out, low interest rates are a result of tight money. It will be interesting to watch and see if central banks can in fact raise interest rates by tightening money. My suspicion is, not for long.

    ReplyDelete