Pages

Friday, September 5, 2008

Is Monetary Policy Really Too Loose?

There has been a lot of discussion recently on the stance of monetary policy. As noted over at Macroblog, many observers believe that monetary policy has been too loose as evidenced by the negative real (or inflation-expectations adjusted) federal funds rate. These observers are concerned that a negative real policy rate may cause, all else equal, inflationary expectations to become unanchored and lead to a repeat of the 1970s-like inflationary spiral. Some observers argue, though, that all else is not equal and that negative real interest rates do not necessarily imply these outcomes. Rather, one must look at real fed funds rate relative to its neutral rate value. Paul McCulley of PIMCO puts it this way:
All sensible discussion of the “right” real Fed funds rate logically must begin with the proposition that the putative “neutral” equilibrium real Fed funds rate is not constant, but rather time varying, a function of financial conditions, notably whether levered financial intermediaries – conventional banks, as well as shadow banks, a term I coined last year at Jackson Hole – are ramping up or ramping down their leverage. The former will lift the “neutral” real rate while the latter will reduce it. Thus, a high Fed funds rate may not be restrictive at all while a low Fed funds rate might not be stimulative at all.
I too agree one should look at the neutral rate value when assessing what the fed funds rate tells us about the stance of monetary policy. However, I would go beyond just financial conditions as suggested by McCulley and also consider productivity growth, intertemporal preferences, and population growth--the determinants of the natural interest rate in a standard growth model-- in assessing the neutral interest rate. Doing so, however, is non-trivial task and many sophisticated econometric attempts have been made with mixed results to estimate the neutral rate.

One easy way to get a sense of whether the fed funds rate is near its neutral rate is to use what I call the policy rate gap measure: the difference between the year-on-year nominal growth rate of the economy and the federal funds rate. This measure, popular with The Economist magazine and some industry economists, shows monetary policy to be too loose when the federal funds rate is significantly below the economy's nominal growth rate and too tight when it is significantly above it. According to Brian Wesbury, the federal funds rate should be within 1% of the economy's nominal growth rate to be neutral. This measure is convenient because it provides an approximation to a neutral fed funds rate without having to resort to real values. [Both measures are in nominal terms so the inflation component drops out in the differencing.]

I have been highly interested in this measure and have shown previously that it does a good job predicting recessions. One issue that has recently come to my attention, though, is how to best measure the economy's nominal growth rate. Previously, I used nominal GDP in constructing this measure. However, some commentators have pointed to Gross Domestic Income as a better measure of current economic activity. Jeremy Nalewaik, in particular, has shown that “real-time GDI has done a substantially better job recognizing the start of the last several recessions than has real-time GDP.” With these findings in mind I constructed the policy rate gap measure with both GDP and GDI to get a sense of the stance of monetary policy today. Here is what I got (click on to enlarge):


These figure indicates that if GDI is used, monetary policy is indeed neutral as suggested by Paul McCulley. If, however, GDP is used then there is a stronger case that monetary policy has been loose. Currently I am inclined to cast my lot with GDI--the bad economic news today seems to confirm my prior--and conclude monetary policy is more or less neutral. For good measure, I also made note in the graph of the massive Greenspan monetary easing of 2003-2005.

Update: Although it may be clear to some readers, the above post does not explain why the policy rate gap can be considered a measure of the stance of monetary policy. To correct this omission, I turn to The Economist magazine who says the the way to “interpret this [measure] is to see America’s nominal GDP growth as a proxy for the average return on American Inc. If the return is higher than the cost of borrowing[i.e. the interest rate], investment and growth will expand [and vice versa]. Alternatively, one could argue if the real economy is growing faster as the result of productivity gains or population growth (via increased labor supply, which in turn implies a higher marginal product of capital, ceteris paribus) and assuming intertemporal preferences are relatively stable, then the real interest rate should be higher too. Throw in the nominal component to the measures of the real economy and real interest rate and one should see similar movements and/or convergence in the nominal growth rate of the economy and the federal funds rate. If these patterns are absent, then one can argue that monetary policy is causing the real rate to deviate from the rate implied by the fundamentals.

3 comments:

  1. Do you have any view on the appropriateness of ECB and BoE interest rates ? They are much higher than in the US, since they weight inflation more heavily in their loss function.

    ReplyDelete
  2. I have two comments.
    First, there appears to be a long term trend in this chart favoring looser policies. This suggests to me that there is a growing willingness to intervene in market dynamics. That should cause some concern for free market advocates.
    Second,I am uncomfortable with a definition of market neutral that is depends on whether levered financial intermediaries are ramping up or ramping down their leverage. This is not too different from a change in requirements for bank capital. They both effect multipliers. They bot also effect systemic risk factors. Thus, this notion of market neutral interest rates is indifferent to moral risk.

    ReplyDelete
  3. Anonymous 1:

    I have not looked closely at the ECB and the BoE, but it would be interesting to see if the simple measure holds up in those regions as well.

    Anonymous 2:

    Regarding trends, let's hope at a minimum we do not see a repeat of the spike seen in the measure during the 2003-2005 period. Your second point is interesting.

    ReplyDelete