Houston, we have a a problem. It appears that that total spending in the U.S. economy is slowing, if not outright contracting. Retail sales fell in May while in April personal consumption expenditures stalled. In addition, housing starts and homes sales plummeted in May. Meanwhile, the MZM measure of the money supply has been declining since late 2009. Since these developments indicate that both money (M) and velocity (V) are declining, it is safe to conclude that aggregate demand (PY) is falling too (i.e. MV = PY). Given these developments why isn't the Fed doing more to help the U.S. economy? Surely, it can stabilize MV. Here is what three observers had to say in response to this question:
A second reason may be the Fed is looking at the wrong indicators in determining the stance of monetary policy and thus mistakenly thinks it is being highly accommodative when in fact it is not. In particular, the Fed may believe it is already doing enough by holding its target interest rate, the federal funds rate, close to 0%. That is the impression one gets when reading statements like this one from the FOMC press release for the June 23, 2010 meeting:
This unintended tightening of monetary policy seems to be the message coming from the difference between the nominal interest rate on the 5-year Treasury and the real interest rate on the 5-year Treasury inflation protected security (TIPS). This difference or spread amounts to the markets expectation of future inflation. Below, this spread is graphed for the first half of this year up through June 24, 2010.
There is a clear downward trend in inflation expectations. Given the developments mentioned above and the other looming economic problems (Eurozone uncertainty, austerity talk, weak household balance sheets, etc.) the most obvious way to interpret this decline is that the markets expect aggregate demand to weaken going forward. Now it is possible that an increase in the liquidity premium is driving some of this decline, but I am not convinced it undermines my interpretation for several reasons. First, such a change in the liquidity premium would itself be driven by the recent uptick in perceived market risk, but that development has only happened in the last month or so as seen in the figure below. The decline in expected inflation has been going on for six months.
1. David Leonhardt. Financial markets are fragile and the Fed does not want to upset the market's confidence in the U.S. government by further easing of monetary policy. More monetary stimulus might just be the trigger to spook markets into dumping the dollar and U.S. debt.There may be some truth in these responses, but let me add two more potential reasons for the Fed's inaction. First, the Fed may believe that some of the problems in the economy may be real in nature rather nominal and if so there is little monetary policy could do to improve matters. For example, if the Fed believes the high level of unemployment is mostly of the structural kind rather than cyclical then there is only a downside to further easing. This probably isn't a big factor--see the Atlanta Fed and the Ryan Avent on this issue--in the Fed officials' thinking but on the margin it may give them another reason to be reluctant to ease.
2. Daniel Gross: The Fed is exhausted from its grand experiments in central banking--it has already drop interest rates to 0%, created new lender-of-last-resort facilities, and blew up its balance sheet--and is puttering out from sheer exhaustion.
3. Ryan Avent: There is division within the Fed on whether further monetary stimulus is really necessary. Moreover, even if there were no internal divisions, the Fed leadership may still be reluctant to act because it fears doing so may cause long-run inflation expectations to become unanchored.
A second reason may be the Fed is looking at the wrong indicators in determining the stance of monetary policy and thus mistakenly thinks it is being highly accommodative when in fact it is not. In particular, the Fed may believe it is already doing enough by holding its target interest rate, the federal funds rate, close to 0%. That is the impression one gets when reading statements like this one from the FOMC press release for the June 23, 2010 meeting:
The Committee will maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to 1/4 percent and continues to anticipate that economic conditions, including low rates of resource utilization, subdued inflation trends, and stable inflation expectations, are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for an extended period.Observers, however, like Michael Belongia, Scott Sumner, and Nick Rowe have been arguing for some time that a low federal funds rate can be a misleading indicator of the stance of monetary policy. Even if one sticks with the federal funds rate as an indicator, then folks like Glenn Rudebush would point out that it would need to be about -3% (which it can't because it can't below zero) to be adding the right amount of stimulus. The bottom line is that the Fed may be inadvertently tightening by sitting on a 0% interest rate target and doing nothing.
This unintended tightening of monetary policy seems to be the message coming from the difference between the nominal interest rate on the 5-year Treasury and the real interest rate on the 5-year Treasury inflation protected security (TIPS). This difference or spread amounts to the markets expectation of future inflation. Below, this spread is graphed for the first half of this year up through June 24, 2010.
There is a clear downward trend in inflation expectations. Given the developments mentioned above and the other looming economic problems (Eurozone uncertainty, austerity talk, weak household balance sheets, etc.) the most obvious way to interpret this decline is that the markets expect aggregate demand to weaken going forward. Now it is possible that an increase in the liquidity premium is driving some of this decline, but I am not convinced it undermines my interpretation for several reasons. First, such a change in the liquidity premium would itself be driven by the recent uptick in perceived market risk, but that development has only happened in the last month or so as seen in the figure below. The decline in expected inflation has been going on for six months.
Second, even if spreads are driving the some of the more recent declines in expected inflation one must ask whether the spreads would be going up in the first place had the Fed been stabilizing inflation expectations (and thus aggregate demand) all along. Any way you slice the data it ain't a pretty picture.
So what do you think? Why isn't the Fed doing more?
Update I: Scott Sumner says Ben Bernanke is trying to do more, but is constrained by internal divisions at the Fed. Chalk one up for Ryan Avent.
Update II: The expected inflation chart was updated one day to June 24.
David
ReplyDeleteFollowing your comment on Scott's blog: I certainly do think, as I said there, that this is primarily a political issue. There are winners from inflation and winners from deflation. I had always thought that the Democrats represented the people who would win from inflation (debtors) - but sadly, with Obama, that seems to not be true. That is very much too bad.
A famous American once said: "We will not be crucified upon a cross of gold."
Perhaps - and perhaps not. I think it is up to Obama - but there is little evidence that he agrees.
JimP
Maybe the real question should be, "Why does the Fed even exist? And why should the American taxpayer trust that the shadowy Fed has his best intentions in mind?"
ReplyDeleteWe'll simply austerity our way out of it.
ReplyDeleteIf you look at the break even inflation 5 years in 5 years there is a break during the first part of May. This can be interpreted as the potential impact of European mess on US demand.
ReplyDeleteSo what can Bernanke do in that case ?
Anonymous #3:
ReplyDeleteThe way I interpret European mess in May is that it is increased uncertainty in financial markets. And this uncertainty has caused a spike in the demand for highly liquid assets, particularly money. Such increases in money demand should be offset by Fed easing.
Anonymous #3:
ReplyDeleteOne follow up thought. It would be a lot easier for the Fed to respond to such shocks if there existed a NGDP futures markets. The Fed could set a target NGDP and intervene until the futures market was in line with its objective.
"I had always thought that the Democrats represented the people who would win from inflation (debtors) - but sadly, with Obama, that seems to not be true." It looks true to me--how is the current disinflation helping the Democrats? The mid-term elections are likely to be catastrophic for them. The mystery is why Obama and the other leaders don't see this.
ReplyDeleteNope. The fundamental reason the Fed isn't doing more is that Ben Bernanke is incompetent.
ReplyDeleteThat's it.
This Fed believes in the same policy Wednesday as it did Monday no matter what happened Tuesday... There's no consistently. When we get surprise numbers on deflation, the Fed changes nothing. When we get surprisingly bad numbers on unemployment, the Fed does nothing. When there is a debt crisis in Europe, the Fed does nothing. Of course, if Monetary posture is just right after these events, then it must have been waaay too accomodative before. But, clearly, that's not the case or these things wouldn't have happened.