So Japan's Prime Minister Shinzo Abe has decided to adopt a NGDP level target:
Formally re-elected head of the ruling party, Prime Minister Shinzo Abe said Thursday he has set out three new goals for “Abenomics” and will target a 20 percent increase in gross domestic product to ¥600 trillion.
The details are murky, but what is clear is that for this plan is to work it will require a credible commitment to permanently expand the monetary base, as shown by Michael Woodford, Paul Krguman, William Buiter, and many others. But was not this already supposed to be happening? Was not Abenomics to permanently double the monetary base? Recall this figure of Japan's monetary base:
Some observers like Hausman and Weisman worry that Abenomic's monetary base expansion is not credible and therefore not permanent. If so, then this latest Abe goal of raising the level of NGDP by 20% may not be credible either.
Or maybe not. One way to check whether the monetary base expansion is expected to be at least somewhat permanent is to see whether nominal spending has been rising. If Abenomics is just a larger version of Japan's 2001-2006 QE program where the monetary base expansion was temporary and did little to raise aggregate demand, then we should expect to see similar patterns in nominal expenditures under Abenomics. So what has actually happened?
The figure above shows that Abenomics compared to the 2001-2006 QE
program has been fairly successful in generating aggregate
demand growth. This suggests that the monetary base growth is seen at least as somewhat
permanent.
Raising the level of NGDP from ¥499 to ¥600 trillion is a far bigger task. Below are three different growth paths for NGDP to reach its new target: a three-year path, a five-year path, and a seven year path. Although no official time table has been set for hitting the ¥600 trillion target, many observers are mentioning 2020 as the target date. As Simon James Cox notes, this time frame seems to be corroborated by Japan's Cabinet Office. This would correspond to the five-year path. If NGDP were to follow the trend growth of NGDP during Abenomics it would follow the seven-year path.
It is worth repeating, as I often do, that the more credible this policy becomes the less need there is for additional growth in the monetary base. If the public perceives the government is firmly committed to permanently expanding the monetary base then its velocity will grow as the public tries to rebalance their portfolios away from it. This increase in monetary base velocity, then, will do much of the heavy lifting in raising aggregate demand growth.
The question is whether a 20% increase in NGDP is a credible goal. It is one thing for Abenomics to gain some credibility, but a 20% NGDP increase in five years? I want to believe, but I am a bit skeptical.
Most of the NGDP growth completed under Abenomics has resulted in higher inflation rather than in higher real GDP growth. The figures below show the inflation rates for the GDP deflator and the core consumer prices in Japan. These increases in inflation have not been matched by sustained increases in real growth. Real GDP has average 0.58% year-on-year growth every quarter since 2013:Q1 whereas the deflator has average 0.93% growth.
One could argue that this higher level of inflation would reduce real debt burdens, ease excess money demand, lower real rates, and increase real economic activity in a way that has not been seen yet. This may be true, but that these developments have not happened speaks to why a 20% NGDP increase may not be credible. Abenomics may have been tolerated, but would an aging population and others holding government debt tolerate five more years of higher inflation? I am not so sure.
Another issue that complicates matters is that raising NGDP growth alone will not solve all Japan's problems. It has numerous structural problems that need to be addressed. These were supposed to be tackled in third arrow of Abenomics. Not much has happened here and maybe more robust NGDP growth would make it easier to address the structural problems.
I do not want to be too pessimistic here. Abenomics successfully raised NGDP growth compared to the 2001-2006 QE program. That is a real accomplishment and speaks to possibility of doing more. I just worry that a 20% NGDP target in five years might be asking too much given the amount of credibility it requires.
Update: One can view this NGDP credibility problem through the lenses of the fiscal theory of the price level. Below is an excerpt from an earlier post:
Paul Krugman [notes] that there could be too much fiscal credibility. If so, it would be creating a drag on aggregate demand growth (i.e. higher expected future surpluses imply lower velocity today and, in turn, mean lower aggregate demand growth). While this argument may apply to the United States, Krugman is certain it applies to Japan. Here is Krugman discussing the proposed tax hikes in Japan:Interestingly, John Cochrane the made the same point in his 2011 paper:I see no prospect that Japan will put off the tax hike forever. But even if it were true, this is credibility Japan wants to lose.
After all, suppose investors conclude that Japan will never raise taxes enough to service its debt. What would they think would happen instead? Not default — Japan doesn’t have to default, because its debts are in its own currency. No, what they might fear is monetization: Japan will print lots of yen to cover deficits. And this will lead to inflation. So a loss of fiscal credibility would lead to expectations of future inflation, which is a problem for Abe’s efforts to, um, get people to expect inflation rather than deflation, because … what?
Long ago I argued that what Japan needed was a credible promise to be irresponsible. And deficits that must be monetized are one way to make that happen...
The last time these issues came up was Japanese monetary and fiscal policy in the 1990s... Quantitative easing and huge fiscal deficits were all tried, and did not lead to inflation or much‘‘stimulus’’. Why not? The answer must be that people were simply not convinced that the government would fail to pay off its debts. Critics of the Japanese government essentially point out their statements sounded pretty lukewarm about commitment to the inflationary project, perhaps wisely. In the end their ‘‘quantitative easing’’ was easily and quickly reversed, showing those expectations at least to have been reasonable.
What Krugman and Cochrane are saying is that there may be too much fiscal credibility in Japan to allow the public to believe current and future monetary base expansions will be permanent. The interesting question, then, is whether the announcement of this NGDP target changes that credibility.
Update II: See John Cochrane's post on Japan. He briefly responds to this post in an update.
Update II: See John Cochrane's post on Japan. He briefly responds to this post in an update.
"This IMF study lends support to this view. It shows It shows that economies with large numbers of old people tend to experience lower inflation rates. This suggests they have political influence."
ReplyDeleteLInk to the imf study is broken. can you please provide a reference?
Thanks for the heads up. It should be fixed now. See page 19.
DeleteProf. Beckworth, you said "One could argue that this higher level of inflation would reduce real debt burdens, ease excess money demand, lower real rates, and increase real economic activity in a way that has not been seen yet. " Higher inflation would reduce government debt burden, that is for sure, but "lower real rates, and increase real economic activity" ? if there were growth opportunities real rates would be higher and that would be a good thing, The fact that probably there aren't many good opportunities is what keeps real rates low, not the opposite. It sounds that you are "reasoning from a price change", a phrase I see a lot in market monetarists' blogs... Having said that, I believe you are right, if there aren't good growth opportunities, higher NGDP will only produce higher inflation and that is probably bad for retirees with political clout. Maybe society will reject those inflation levels, maybe not...
ReplyDeleteSimple, radical idea to instill credibility and provide a tax cut* at the same time: Monetize a small portion of the nations debt with a big announcement. Repeat quarterly, as needed.
ReplyDeleteThis may not be so radical, and I may yet see this happen.
* or postpone a tax increase. Technically, what this does is replace a sales/consumption/income tax with a savings tax (higher inflation).
Hey dwb, in retrospect I was probably a bit too pessimistic in the post. The key, in my view, is to reduce macro credibility enough to spur aggregate demand without losing all macro credibility. My answer is a level target combined with other policy changes.
DeleteI agree with dwb. Monetize tax revenues and give tax cuts. Monetize debt too. If that does not result in inflation it will surely result in higher economic growth and living standards.
ReplyDelete"Was not Abenomics to permanently double the monetary base?"
ReplyDeleteI'm not sure of your meaning here, because I haven't followed the details of Abenomics. What happened? Was there a policy announcement by the monetary authority that it would permanently double the monetary base? And then a reversal of that policy?
maybe backtracking or dilution or wavering are better words than reversal ... my key question is whether or not there was an initial policy announcement from the monetary authority.
Deletei.e. a policy announcement with respect to both doubling and permanence
Delete(sorry for multiple c's)
JKH, yes, the bank of Japan said it planned to double the monetary base. The permanent part is not so explicit, but to jump to 2% inflation from where it has been implies implies permanency. Here is the original statement where it is listed: https://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2013/k130404a.pdf
DeleteJKH, from the official page of the BoJ's Abenomics program (they call it Quantitative and Qualitative Easing, QQE):
Delete"The Bank will continue with the QQE, aiming to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent, as long as it is necessary for maintaining that target"
https://www.boj.or.jp/en/mopo/outline/qqe.htm/
JKH, just did a quick follow up post related to your question. http://macromarketmusings.blogspot.com/2015/09/doubling-down-on-abenomics.html
DeleteThanks David.
ReplyDeleteI forgot that I had put pretty much the same question in a comment at your post last December. That probably means I need more time to sink my teeth into figuring out just what’s bothering me so much about the use of the term “permanent” - which I see most of the notables who believe in the idea are using in roughly the same way. This is a specific dimension to the total subject at hand. There is an element of analytical vagueness that I find uncomfortable. But it needs more work from me, if I can get to it.
Good set of posts and links on the subject in total, and a nice way of catching up on Abenomics.
Nice post
ReplyDelete