There is a new VoxEU ebook on secular stagnation. The book is a collection of essays by many prominent economists, most of whom are proponents of secular stagnation. As readers know, I am not convinced that this problem lingers over the U.S. economy and have explained why at the Washington Post and on this blog. This latest book does nothing to ease my skepticism. Many of the authors continue to mismeasure the real interest rate and ignore what I see as important technology and demographic developments that undermine the case for secular stagnation. Let's review these key issues.
First, real interest rates adjusted for the risk premium have not been in a secular decline. Everyone from Larry Summers to Paul Krugman to Olivier Blanchard ignore this point in the book. They all claim that real interest rates have been trending down for decades. The editors of the book, Coen Teulings and Richard Baldwin, even claim that this development is the 'prima facie' evidence for secular stagnation. What they are doing wrong is only subtracting expected inflation from the observed nominal interest rate. They also need to subtract the risk premium to get the natural interest rate, the interest rate at the heart of the story. For it is the natural interest rate that is affected by expected growth of technology and the labor force.
This point can illustrated by looking at the 10-year treasury yield for the United States (these graphs were first used in my Washington Post piece). The figure below shows the 10-year nominal treasury yield along with its expected inflation and term premium. The former
is the annual average inflation rate expected over the next ten years, while the
latter is the risk premium on treasuries that increases with the holding period
of the security. The expected inflation series is constructed using data from
the Survey
of Professional Forecasters and the Livingston
Survey. The term premium is the average of the Kim-Wright
and Adrian,
Crump, and Moench estimates of the term premium.
Note that both the expected inflation and the term premium begin to grow
in the mid-1960s and peak in the early 1980s. From there, they both experience a secular decline. These developments track the increased uncertainty over the nominal anchor, inflation expectations, and economic policy that occurred during this time.
Many stories are given for why this happened--LBJ trying to do Vietnam
and the Great Society, beginning of the Bretton Woods System breakdown, Fed
using bad economic theory, etc.--but the big point is there was a big
policy break from the past of relative price stability and this shock affected both the risk premium and inflation expectations.
Proponents of secular stagnation only account for the expected inflation term. They subtract it from the observed nominal treasury yield and behold a declining trend in real interest rates is found starting around early 1980, as seen below.
But this is not the risk-free real interest rate, the one that best approximates the natural interest rate idea. To get that, the secular stagnationists need to also subtract the estimated risk premium. This measure, shown below, shows no clear declining trend but does show a stationary-like process that revolves around a mean just about 2%.
Now one could claim a new trend has set in over the last decade, but proving its a trend in this short of time is impossible. Moreover, there is a simpler answer: the deviations around the 2% mean are driven by the business cycle and we just happen to have gone through one of the worst in a long time. The figure below supports this view as it plots the CBO's output gap measure against the 10-year risk-free real interest rate:
To be clear, the 10-year real risk-free rate should be equal to the average
of the expected path of the short-term real risk-free rates over the same
time horizon. The first few years of this interest rate path are determined by the business
cycle, which explains the risk-free rate's correlation with the output
gap as noted above. The remaining years are shaped by expected growth of productivity and
labor force and that explain the roughly 2% trend. Proponents of secular stagnation are effectively claiming the long-term 2% trend is no more. I don't buy it because one, I think they are confusing the trend for the cycle, and two, technology and demographic developments are far better than commonly portrayed. That leads us to our next point.
Second, technology growth appears to be rapidly growing but getting harder to measure. This point has been made recently by Joel Mokyr in the Wall Street Journal and Erik Brynjfolsson and Andrea McAfee in The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies. Their basic point is that the economy
is being radically transformed via smart machines and this will spur a period of great productivity growth, high returns to capital, and more investment. For example, imagine all the new infrastructure spending that will have to be done to support the increased use of driverless cars and trucks. Even over the past few decades there have been meaningful gains as illustrated by this hilarious spoof the show 24 being made in 1994. Noah Smith makes the case for big productivity gain even more recently. The secular stagnationists should take these developments more seriously.
Probably one reason these developments get overlooked is that they are hard to measure. As I noted in my Washington Post piece, a good example can be found in your smartphone. It contains many items you had to formerly purchase separately--books, newspapers, cameras, scanners, bank ATMs, voice recorders, radios, encyclopedias, GPS systems, maps, dictionaries, etc.--and were counted part of GDP. Now most are free and not a part of GDP. My sense is this is not a recent phenomenon, but has been going on for sometime as the economy has become more service orientated. Measuring productivity in the service sector is notoriously hard. And it is only going to get harder.
Here is a great illustration of this measurement problem. Tyler Cowen has made the case that there has been a Great Stagnation in innovation that explains the observed slowdown in productivity data. I looked at the John Fernald TFP data and found this troubling chart. It seemed to confirm the Great Stagnation theory. It showed a sharp break in trend TFP growth starting around 1973:
Tyler Cowen approved of the chart, but Noah Smith raised some good questions about it. He observed that the Fernald TFP data can be decomposed into TFP in investment production and TFP in consumption production. TFP in investment looks better than the overall TFP:
While that is interesting, what is really striking is the TFP in consumption. It has basically flatlined since the early 1970s and is what is driving the Great Stagnation. In the spirit of Tyler Cowen, let's call this segment "The Great Flattening."
The Great Flattening does not seem reasonable. Has productivity growth in consumption really been flat since the early 1970s? No meaningful gains at all? This does not pass the smell test, yet this is one of the best TFP measures. This suggest there are big measurement problems in consumption production. And I suspect they can be traced to the service sector. I suspect if these measurement problems were fixed there would be less support for secular stagnation (and maybe for the Great Stagnation view too).
Third, the demographic outlook is not as dire as the secular stagnationists make it out to be. Bill McBride has been noting for some time that the U.S. demographic outlook is improving as the largest cohort is now found in the Millenial age group. Matt Busigin also makes this point. Globally, the United Nations also forecasts that working-age populations in many parts of the world will grow through 2050. More labor growth implies a higher return to capital and more investment demand.
These are the reason I remain skeptical about secular stagnation and optimistic about future U.S. economic growth. Maybe the secular stagnation story makes sense for the Eurozone, but at a minimum the authors of this VoxEU book should be more cautious in their endorsement of it for the United States. My sense is that they are missing the forest for the trees. They see a five-year slump, the zero lower bound, and a gloomy outlook. From these few bad 'trees' they conclude the entire forest has succumbed to the secular stagnation disease. The evidence above suggests they are wrong. They need to start looking closer at the forest.
Sure looks to me like there's a downward trend in your risk-free real interest rate -- a succession of lower peaks and lower troughs starting in the early 1980's. Of course it follows the output gap; that's kind of the point: with secular stagnation it gets harder to achieve potential, so you need very low interest rates. The output gap looks to me also to have a downward trend, although it doesn't start until the 1990's. (But I"m not sure I agree with the CBO's estimates; my own guess at the output gap has had a downward trend starting in the late 1980's.)
ReplyDeleteAndy, by that reasoning the figure indicates there was secular stagnation in mid-1960 through late 1970s. That doesn't make sense. Again, I see their main point as indicating the trend has changed which to me is implausible.
DeleteI don't see how it indicates that. There are some downward spikes in the 60's and 70's but nothing that resembles the recent downward trend.
DeleteAnd I'd also note that there was nothing that resembled the housing boom of the noughts. The 2006 interest rate peak is suspect because it seems to have been unsustainable. Real interest rates struggled to get back up to the old average at a business cycle peak, and even that seems in retrospect to have required a great deal of fraud and self-delusion on the part of credit market participants.
"But this is not the risk-free real interest rate, the one that best approximates the natural interest rate idea. To get that, the secular stagnationists need to also subtract the estimated risk premium."
ReplyDeleteYes. And they also need to remove the liquidity premia on 10-year Treasuries in order to get to the natural rate. Nominal rates may have come down not because of a secular decline in the natural rate, but steady technological improvements in the structure of bond markets that have improved the liquidity of bonds.
http://jpkoning.blogspot.ca/2013/04/beyond-bond-bubbles-liquidity-adjusted.html
Until then, who knows what the natural rate actually looks like.
I think 'risk premium' is being used loosely here because it is really an estimated term premium. The latter is a broader concept and should include any liquidity premium.
DeleteYou can have liquidity premium without term premium, for instance a 6-year T-bond and a 6-year fixed insured deposit may have different prices despite equal terms, the difference arising because of the superior liquidity of the bond.
DeleteDavid, I am with you. They see declining potential and thus see lower real rates. However, the lower potential is increasing at normal real rates. The potential is simply being undermined by declining relative economic power of labor. Instead of a secular decline, we are seeing an institutional change in the economic structure.
ReplyDeleteProductivity is being constrained by low labor share and constrained demand. I point to your TFP in consumption chart. Labor share has even fallen tremendously in China since 2000.
My view is that if labor share was to rise significantly in many advanced countries, we would see a nice reversal of this secular stagnation. But labor share could not rise so quickly without firms overly reacting. So it will take time and changing global conditions to reverse the secular downward trend in labor share. Labor has to gain power in many countries and secular stagnation will begin to disappear.
I believe there is also another side to that story: banking and finance regulations have increased the demand for Treasuries since 1980s.
ReplyDeleteI used some of the charts above in my own post on that topic here:
http://spontaneousfinance.com/2014/08/18/secular-stagnation-factoring-in-banking-regulation/
Not much to explain. Financial innovation (as measured by demand deposit turnover), rose sharply from 65 until 81. Then Congress turned 38,000 financial intermediaries into 38,000 CBs (adding to the 14,000 we already had). Then, c. 1995 banks became "unbound", financial engineering accelerated, and finally the Fed introduced the payment of interest on excess reserve balances.
ReplyDelete