Jim Hamilton is not a big fan of this equation:
MV = PY,
This is the famous equation of exchange where M is the money supply, V is velocity, P is the price level, and Y is real GDP. Back in 2009 he questioned Scott Sumner's use of it in thinking about the economic crisis. I replied that though it was just an accounting identity, it still shed some light on the economic crisis in its expanded form. Now he is questioning its use as a way to measure velocity. He correctly notes that velocity is nothing more than a residual from this accounting identity, whose value can change based on what measure of the money supply one uses (i.e. V =[PY]/M). He further questions its usefulness by noting in several figures that M1's growth rates seem to be almost perfectly offset by changes in velocity's growth rate. Here is a figure that reproduces Hamilton's M1 graphs for the 1980-2010 period. (Click on figure to enlarge.)
Yes, it is rather striking in this figure that the growth rate of M1 and M1 velocity tend to move in almost perfectly opposite directions. But why should the growth rates of M1 and M1 velocity necessarily move in opposite directions? Hamilton's critique, as I understand it, is that they should move inversely because velocity is simply a residual in the equation of exchange. But this understanding hinges on the assumption that nominal GDP growth is relatively stable. But nominal GDP growth has not always been stable. It just so happens, however, that most of the time in Hamiltion's 1980-2010 figures cover the "Great Moderation", the period when the Fed did a relatively good job of stabilizing nominal spending. One would therefore expect the changes in the money supply to largely offset changes in velocity during this time. The Fed was doing its job. The near symmetry in the figure is a testament to its success.
Now if one looks outside the 1980-2010 period this symmetry is harder to find. Here is the 1960-1979 period with the same series: (Click on figure to enlarge.)
The lack of symmetry here is not particularly surprising. The Fed's performance in stabilizing the growth of nominal spending was abysmal during this time, as shown by Josh Hendrickson. Along these same lines, there are points in the 1980-2010 figure where the symmetry is missing. They all occur during recessions. These are cases where the Fed failed to adequately stabilize NGDP.
I find these figures, motivated by the equation of exchange, insightful. They show there is merit in using the equation of exchange. Moreover, if one looks to the expanded equation of exchange form as done here there is much insight this identity can brig to bear on the economic crisis.
Update: Nick Rowe explains these pictures using Milton Friedman's thermostat. Meanwhile, Arnold Kling provides an alternative interpretation of the data.
Update: Nick Rowe explains these pictures using Milton Friedman's thermostat. Meanwhile, Arnold Kling provides an alternative interpretation of the data.
Well it is of course a tautology, so you can always use it as a framework for discussion.
ReplyDeleteHowever, the US problems are surely real not monetary in origin. Robert Gordon has shown that potential GDP growth has declined. Consistent with this is the observed low level of investment in capital and labor.
The American empire is in decline. MV=PQ has nothing useful to say about that.
Milton Friedman's thermostat analogy:
ReplyDeleteIf a house has a good thermostat, we should see no correlation between the inside temperature (NGDP) and the amount of oil burned in the furnace (M).
We should also see no correlation between the inside temperature (NGDP) and the outside temperature (V).
And we should see a strong correlation between the outside temperature (V) and the amount of oil burned (M).
"The contrast between the periods before and after the middle of the 1980s is
ReplyDeleteremarkable. Before, it is like a chart of the temperature in a room without a
thermostat in a location with very variable climate; after, it is like the temperature
in the same room but with a reasonably good though not perfect thermostat, and
one that is set to a gradually declining temperature. Sometime around 1985, the Fed
appears to have acquired the thermostat that it had been seeking the whole of its
life."
http://www.google.ca/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=1&sqi=2&ved=0CBgQFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Ffaculty.hacc.edu%2Ferandolph%2FTake_%2520Home%2FThermostat_2.pdf&rct=j&q=The%20Fed%27s%20Thermostat&ei=xI8STdOwA4Kr8AbziKH4DQ&usg=AFQjCNE0FDN5ThzeTH7pVxM_gCNpCMUx1w&cad=rja
I think I completely befuddled JDH when I told him off for such poor posting. He was expecting criticism from the inflationistas and instead he got hit hard from a fan of NGDP targeting.
ReplyDeleteNick:
ReplyDeleteThat is a great analogy. Glad to see your post on it too. Did you see Arnold Kling's reply?
Mark:
Yes, I saw your comments there and was silently cheering you on.
"velocity is nothing more than a residual from this accounting identity, whose value can change based on what measure of the money supply one uses"
ReplyDeleteAnd don't forget that Y does not represent total production of goods. It just represents the quantity of goods bought with the money designated as M.
Of course, the definition of M is also arbitrary...